Technological unemployment

From KYNNpedia
Revision as of 23:32, 28 February 2024 by imported>Swinub (→‎20th century)
(diff) ← Older revision | Latest revision (diff) | Newer revision → (diff)

In the 21st century, robots are beginning to perform roles not just in manufacturing but also in the service sector – in healthcare, for example.

Template:Automation

Technological unemployment is the loss of jobs caused by technological change.<ref>Peters, Michael A. (2020). "Beyond technological unemployment: the future of work". Educational Philosophy and Theory. 52 (5): 485–491. doi:10.1080/00131857.2019.1608625.</ref><ref>Peters, Michael A. (2017). "Technological unemployment: Educating for the fourth industrial revolution". Educational Philosophy and Theory. 49 (1): 1–6. doi:10.1080/00131857.2016.1177412. hdl:10289/10955.</ref><ref>Kim, Young Joon; Kim, Kyungsoo; Lee, SuKyoung (2017). "The rise of technological unemployment and its implications on the future macroeconomic landscape". Futures. 87: 1–9. doi:10.1016/j.futures.2017.01.003.</ref><ref>Lima, Yuri; Barbosa, Carlos Eduardo; dos Santos, Herbert Salazar; de Souza, Jano Moreira (2021). "Understanding Technological Unemployment: A Review of Causes, Consequences, and Solutions". Societies. 11 (2): 50. doi:10.3390/soc11020050.</ref> It is a key type of structural unemployment. Technological change typically includes the introduction of labour-saving "mechanical-muscle" machines or more efficient "mechanical-mind" processes (automation), and humans' role in these processes are minimized.<ref>Chuang, Szufang; Graham, Carroll Marion (3 September 2018). "Embracing the sobering reality of technological influences on jobs, employment and human resource development: A systematic literature review". European Journal of Training and Development. 42 (7/8): 400–416. doi:10.1108/EJTD-03-2018-0030. ISSN 2046-9012. S2CID 169359498.</ref> Just as horses were gradually made obsolete as transport by the automobile and as labourer by the tractor, humans' jobs have also been affected throughout modern history. Historical examples include artisan weavers reduced to poverty after the introduction of mechanized looms. During World War II, Alan Turing's bombe machine compressed and decoded thousands of man-years worth of encrypted data in a matter of hours. A contemporary example of technological unemployment is the displacement of retail cashiers by self-service tills and cashierless stores.

That technological change can cause short-term job losses is widely accepted. The view that it can lead to lasting increases in unemployment has long been controversial. Participants in the technological unemployment debates can be broadly divided into optimists and pessimists. Optimists agree that innovation may be disruptive to jobs in the short term, yet hold that various compensation effects ensure there is never a long-term negative impact on jobs, whereas pessimists contend that at least in some circumstances, new technologies can lead to a lasting decline in the total number of workers in employment. The phrase "technological unemployment" was popularised by John Maynard Keynes in the 1930s, who said it was "only a temporary phase of maladjustment".<ref>The Economic Possibilities of our Grandchildren (1930). E McGaughey, 'Will Robots Automate Your Job Away? Full Employment, Basic Income, and Economic Democracy' (2022) 51(3) Industrial Law Journal 511, part 2(2)</ref> The issue of machines displacing human labour has been discussed since at least Aristotle's time.<ref>Bhorat, Ziyaad (2022). "Automation, Slavery, and Work in Aristotle's Politics Book I". Polis: The Journal for Ancient Greek and Roman Political Thought. 39 (2): 279–302. doi:10.1163/20512996-12340366. S2CID 250252042.</ref><ref>Devecka, Martin (2013). "Did the Greeks Believe in Their Robots?". The Cambridge Classical Journal. 59: 52–69. doi:10.1017/S1750270513000079.</ref>

Prior to the 18th century, both the elite and common people would generally take the pessimistic view on technological unemployment, at least in cases where the issue arose. Due to generally low unemployment in much of pre-modern history, the topic was rarely a prominent concern. In the 18th century fears over the impact of machinery on jobs intensified with the growth of mass unemployment, especially in Great Britain which was then at the forefront of the Industrial Revolution. Yet some economic thinkers began to argue against these fears, claiming that overall innovation would not have negative effects on jobs. These arguments were formalised in the early 19th century by the classical economists. During the second half of the 19th century, it stayed apparent that technological progress was benefiting all sections of society, including the working class. Concerns over the negative impact of innovation diminished. The term "Luddite fallacy" was coined to describe the thinking that innovation would have lasting harmful effects on employment.

The view that technology is unlikely to lead to long-term unemployment has been repeatedly challenged by a minority of economists.[who?] In the early 1800s these included David Ricardo himself. There were dozens of economists warning about technological unemployment during brief intensifications of the debate that spiked in the 1930s and 1960s. Especially in Europe, there were further warnings in the closing two decades of the twentieth century, as commentators noted an enduring rise in unemployment suffered by many industrialised nations since the 1970s. Yet a clear majority of both professional economists and the interested general public held the optimistic view through most of the 20th century.

In the second decade of the 21st century, a number of studies have been released suggesting that technological unemployment may increase worldwide. Oxford Professors Carl Benedikt Frey and Michael Osborne, for example, have estimated that 47 percent of U.S. jobs are at risk of automation.<ref>Frey, Carl Benedikt; Osborne, Michael A (1 January 2017). "The future of employment: How susceptible are jobs to computerisation?". Technological Forecasting and Social Change. 114: 254–280. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.395.416. doi:10.1016/j.techfore.2016.08.019. ISSN 0040-1625.</ref> However, their methodology has been challenged as lacking evidential foundation and criticised for implying that technology (rather than social policy) creates unemployment rather than redundancies.<ref>E McGaughey, 'Will Robots Automate Your Job Away? Full Employment, Basic Income, and Economic Democracy' (2022) 51(3) Industrial Law Journal 511</ref> On the PBS NewsHours the authors defended their findings and clarified they do necessarily imply future technological unemployment.<ref>"Are we on the brink of a jobless future?". PBS NewsHour. 31 August 2017. Retrieved 15 December 2017.</ref> While many[which?][who?] economists and commentators still argue such fears are unfounded, as was widely accepted for most of the previous two centuries, concern over technological unemployment is growing once again.<ref>"In the Future, Will Everyone Be Unemployed?". 4 August 2014.</ref><ref>Censky, Annalyn. "What 0% unemployment looks like". CNN.</ref><ref name="Thompson2015">Thompson, Derek (July–August 2015). "A World Without Work". The Atlantic. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> A report in Wired in 2017 quotes knowledgeable people such as economist Gene Sperling and management professor Andrew McAfee on the idea that handling existing and impending job loss to automation is a "significant issue".[why?]<ref name="Dreyfuss_2017-03-24">Dreyfuss, Emily (24 March 2017), "Hate to break it to Steve Mnuchin, but AI's already taking jobs", Wired</ref> Recent technological innovations have the potential to displace humans in the professional, white-collar, low-skilled, creative fields, and other "mental jobs".<ref>Porte, Eduardo; Manjoo, Farhad (9 March 2016). "A Future Without Jobs? Two Views of the Changing Work Force". The New York Times.</ref><ref name="Thompson2015" /> The World Bank's World Development Report 2019 argues that while automation displaces workers,Template:Quantify technological innovation creates moreTemplate:Quantify new industries and jobs on balance.<ref>"The Changing Nature of Work". Retrieved 8 October 2018.</ref>

History

Classical era

Roman Emperor Vespasian, who refused a low-cost method of transport of heavy goods that would put laborers out of work

According to author Gregory Woirol, the phenomenon of technological unemployment is likely to have existed since at least the invention of the wheel.<ref>Woirol 1996, p. 17</ref> Ancient societies had various methods for relieving the poverty of those unable to support themselves with their own labour. Ancient China and ancient Egypt may have had various centrally run relief programmes in response to technological unemployment dating back to at least the second millennium BC.<ref name="reflief"> "Relief". The San Bernardino County Sun. California. 3 March 1940. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref> Ancient Hebrews and adherents of the ancient Vedic religion had decentralised responses where aiding the poor was encouraged by their faiths.<ref name="reflief" /> In ancient Greece, large numbers of free labourersTemplate:Quantify could find themselves unemployed due to both the effects of ancient labour saving technology and to competition from slaves ("machines of flesh and blood"<ref>Forbes 1932, p2</ref>). Sometimes, these unemployed workers would starve to death or were forced into slavery themselves although in other cases they were supported by handouts. Pericles responded to perceived technological unemployment by launching public works programmes to provide paid work to the jobless. Some people[who?] criticized Pericle's programmes as wasting public money but were defeated.<ref>Forbes 1932, pp24 -30</ref>

Perhaps the earliest example of a scholar discussing the phenomenon of technological unemployment occurs with Aristotle, who speculated in Book One of Politics that if machines could become sufficiently advanced, there would be no more need for human labour.<ref> Campa, Riccardo (February 2014). "Technological Growth and Unemployment: A Global Scenario Analysis". Journal of Evolution and Technology. ISSN 1541-0099. </ref> Similar to the Greeks, ancient Romans responded to the problem of technological unemployment by relieving poverty with handouts (such as the Cura Annonae). Several hundred thousand families were sometimes supported like this at once.<ref name="reflief"/> Less often, jobs were directly created with public works programmes, such as those launched by the Gracchi. Various emperors even went as far as to refuse or ban labour saving innovations.<ref>Forbes 1993, chapter 2</ref><ref>Forbes 1932, passim, see esp. pp. 49–53</ref> In one instance, the introduction of a labor-saving invention was blocked, when Emperor Vespasian refused to allow a new method of low-cost transportation of heavy goods, saying "You must allow my poor hauliers to earn their bread."<ref>See book eight, chapt XVIII of Suetonius's The Twelve Caesars.</ref> Labour shortages began to develop in the Roman empire towards the end of the second century AD, and from this point mass unemployment in Europe appears to have largely receded for over a millennium.<ref>Forbes 1932, pp147 -150</ref>

Post-classical era

The medieval and early renaissance period saw the widespread adoption of newly invented technologies, as well as older ones which had been conceived yet barely used in the Classical era.<ref> Roberto Sabatino Lopez (1976). "Chpt. 2,3". The Commercial Revolution of the Middle Ages, 950-1350. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0521290463.</ref> Some were invented in Europe while others were invented in more Eastern countries like China, India, Arabia and Persia. The Black Death left fewer workers across Europe. Mass unemployment began to reappear in Europe, especially in Western, Central and Southern Europe in the 15th century, partly as a result of population growth, and partly due to changes in the availability of land for subsistence farming caused by early enclosures.<ref name="Schumpeter 1987 loc= Chpt 6">Schumpeter 1987, Chpt 6</ref> As a result of the threat of unemployment, there was less tolerance for disruptive new technologies. European authorities would often side with groups representing subsections of the working population, such as Guilds, banning new technologies and sometimes even executing those who tried to promote or trade in them.<ref>On occasion these executions were carried out with methods normally reserved for only the worst criminals, for example on a single occasion in the south of France, 58 people were broken on the Catherine wheel for selling forbidden goods. See Chpt 1 of The Worldly Philosophers.</ref>

16th to 18th century

Elizabeth I, who refused to patent a knitting machine invented by William Lee, saying "Consider thou what the invention could do to my poor subjects. It would assuredly bring them to ruin by depriving them of employment, thus making them beggars."

In Great Britain, the ruling elite began to take a less restrictive approach to innovation somewhat earlier than in much of continental Europe, which has been cited as a possible reason for Britain's early lead in driving the Industrial Revolution.<ref>E.g by Sir John Habakkuk in American and British Technology in the Nineteenth Century (1962), Cambridge University Press – Habakkuk also went on to say that due to labour shortages, compared with their British counterparts there was far less resistance from U.S. workers to the introduction of technology, leading to more update of innovation, and hence to the more efficient American system of manufacturing</ref> Yet concern over the impact of innovation on employment remained strong through the 16th and early 17th century. A famous example of new technology being refused occurred when the inventor William Lee invited Queen Elizabeth I to view a labour saving knitting machine. The Queen declined to issue a patent on the grounds that the technology might cause unemployment among textile workers. After moving to France and also failing to achieve success in promoting his invention, Lee returned to England but was again refused by Elizabeth's successor James I for the same reason.<ref name="Martin"/>

After the Glorious Revolution, authorities became less sympathetic to workers concerns about losing their jobs due to innovation. An increasingly influential strand of Mercantilist thought held that introducing labour saving technology would actually reduce unemployment, as it would allow British firms to increase their market share against foreign competition. From the early 18th century workers could no longer rely on support from the authorities against the perceived threat of technological unemployment. They would sometimes take direct action, such as machine breaking, in attempts to protect themselves from disruptive innovation. Joseph Schumpeter notes that as the 18th century progressed, thinkers would raise the alarm about technological unemployment with increasing frequency, with von Justi being a prominent example.<ref>Schumpeter 1987, Chpt 4</ref> Yet Schumpeter also notes that the prevailing view among the elite solidified on the position that technological unemployment would not be a long-term problem.<ref name="Martin"/><ref name="Schumpeter 1987 loc= Chpt 6"/>

19th century

It was only in the 19th century that debates over technological unemployment became intense, especially in Great Britain where many economic thinkers of the time were concentrated. Building on the work of Dean Tucker and Adam Smith, political economists began to create what would become the modern discipline of economics.<ref group="note">Smith did not directly address the problem of technological unemployment, but the Dean had, saying in 1757 that in the long term, the introduction of machinery would allow more employment than would have been possible without them.</ref> While rejecting much of mercantilism, members of the new discipline largely agreed that technological unemployment would not be an enduring problem. In the first few decades of the 19th century, several prominent political economists did, however, argue against the optimistic view, claiming that innovation could cause long-term unemployment. These included Sismondi,<ref name="Sowell_2006">Sowell, T. (2006), "Chapter 5: Sismondi: A Neglected Pioneer", On Classical Economics</ref> Malthus, J S Mill, and from 1821, David Ricardo himself.<ref>While initially of the view that innovation benefited the whole population, Ricardo was persuaded by Malthus that technology could both push down wages for the working class, and cause long-term unemployment. He famously expressed these views in a chapter called "on Machinery", added to the third and final (1821) edition of On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation</ref> As arguably the most respected political economist of his age, Ricardo's view was challenging to others in the discipline. The first major economist to respond was Jean-Baptiste Say, who argued that no one would introduce machinery if they were going to reduce the amount of product,<ref group="note">Typically the introduction of machinery would both increase output and lower cost per unit.</ref> and that as Say's Law states that supply creates its own demand, any displaced workers would automatically find work elsewhere once the market had had time to adjust.<ref>Bartlett, Bruce (18 January 2014). "Is industrial innovation destroying jobs?". Cato Journal. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref> Ramsey McCulloch expanded and formalised Say's optimistic views on technological unemployment, and was supported by others such as Charles Babbage, Nassau Senior and many other lesser known political economists. Towards the middle of the 19th century, Karl Marx joined the debates. Building on the work of Ricardo and Mill, Marx went much further, presenting a deeply pessimistic view of technological unemployment; his views attracted many followers and founded an enduring school of thought but mainstream economics was not dramatically changed. By the 1870s, at least in Great Britain, technological unemployment faded both as a popular concern and as an issue for academic debate. It had become increasingly apparent that innovation was increasing prosperity for all sections of British society, including the working class. As the classical school of thought gave way to neoclassical economics, mainstream thinking was tightened to take into account and refute the pessimistic arguments of Mill and Ricardo.<ref>Woirol 1996, pp. 2, 20–22</ref>

20th century

Critics of the view that innovation causes lasting unemployment argue that technology is used by workers and does not replace them on a large scale.

For the first two decades of the 20th century, mass unemployment was not the major problem it had been in the first half of the 19th. While the Marxist school and a few other thinkers continued to challenge the optimistic view, technological unemployment was not a significant concern for mainstream economic thinking until the mid to late 1920s. In the 1920s mass unemployment re-emerged as a pressing issue within Europe. At this time the U.S. was generally more prosperous, but even there urban unemployment had begun to increase from 1927. Rural American workers had been suffering job losses from the start of the 1920s; many had been displaced by improved agricultural technology, such as the tractor. The centre of gravity for economic debates had by this time moved from Great Britain to the United States, and it was here that the 20th century's two great periods of debate over technological unemployment largely occurred.<ref>Woirol 1996, pp. 2, 8–12</ref>

The peak periods for the two debates were in the 1930s and the 1960s. According to economic historian Gregory R Woirol, the two episodes share several similarities.<ref name="Woirol 1996 loc= pp. 8 - 12">Woirol 1996, pp. 8–12</ref> In both cases academic debates were preceded by an outbreak of popular concern, sparked by recent rises in unemployment. In both cases the debates were not conclusively settled, but faded away as unemployment was reduced by an outbreak of war – World War II for the debate of the 1930s, and the Vietnam War for the 1960s episodes. In both cases, the debates were conducted within the prevailing paradigm at the time, with little reference to earlier thought. In the 1930s, optimists based their arguments largely on neo-classical beliefs in the self-correcting power of markets to reduce any short-term unemployment via compensation effects. In the 1960s, belief in compensation effects was less strong, but the mainstream Keynesian economists of the time largely believed government intervention would be able to counter any persistent technological unemployment that was not cleared by market forces. Another similarity was the publication of a major Federal study towards the end of each episode, which broadly found that long-term technological unemployment was not occurring (though the studies did agree innovation was a major factor in the short term displacement of workers, and advised government action to provide assistance).<ref group="note">In the 1930s, this study was Unemployment and technological change(Report no. G-70, 1940) by Corrington Calhoun Gill of the 'National Research Project on Reemployment Opportunities and Recent changes in Industrial Techniques'. Some earlier Federal reports took a pessimistic view of technological unemployment, e.g. Memorandum on Technological Unemployment (1933) by Ewan Clague Bureau of Labor Statistics. Some authorities – e.g. Udo Sautter in Chpt 5 of Three Cheers for the Unemployed: Government and Unemployment Before the New Deal (Cambridge University Press, 1991) – say that in the early 1930s there was near consensus among US experts that technological unemployment was a major problem. Other's though like Bruce Bartlett in Is Industrial Innovation Destroying Jobs (Cato Journal 1984) argue that most economists remained optimistic even during the 1930s. In the 1960s episode, the major Federal study that bookmarked the end of the period of intense debate was Technology and the American economy (1966) by the 'National Commission on Technology, Automation, and Economic Progress' established by president Lyndon Johnson in 1964 Archived 4 March 2016 at the Wayback Machine</ref><ref name="Woirol 1996 loc= pp. 8 - 12"/>

As the golden age of capitalism came to a close in the 1970s, unemployment once again rose, and this time generally remained relatively high for the rest of the century, across most advanced economies. Several economists once again argued that this may be due to innovation, with perhaps the most prominent being Paul Samuelson.<ref>Samuelson, Paul (1989). "Ricardo Was Right!". The Scandinavian Journal of Economics. 91 (1): 47–62. doi:10.2307/3440162. JSTOR 3440162.</ref> Overall, the closing decades of the 20th century saw most concern expressed over technological unemployment in Europe, though there were several examples in the U.S.<ref>Woirol 1996, pp. 143–144</ref> A number of popular works warning of technological unemployment were also published. These included James S. Albus's 1976 book titled Peoples' Capitalism: The Economics of the Robot Revolution;<ref name="peoplescapbook">James S. Albus, Peoples' Capitalism: The Economics of the Robot Revolution Archived 4 March 2016 at the Wayback Machine (free download)</ref><ref name="peoplescap">James S. Albus, People's Capitalism main website</ref> David F. Noble with works published in 1984<ref name="Noble1984">Noble 1984</ref> and 1993;<ref name="Noble1993">Noble 1993.</ref> Jeremy Rifkin and his 1995 book The End of Work;<ref name="Rifkin1995">Rifkin 1995</ref> and the 1996 book The Global Trap.<ref>The Global Trap defines a possible "20/80 society" that may emerge in the 21st century. In this potential society, 20% of the working age population will be enough to keep the world economy going. The authors describe how at a conference at the invitation of Mikhail Gorbachev with 500 leading politicians, business leaders and academics from all continents from 27 September – 1 October 1995 at the Fairmont Hotel in San Francisco, the term "one-fifth-society" arose. The authors describe an increase in productivity caused by the decrease in the amount of work, so this could be done by one-fifth of the global labor force and leave four-fifths of the working age people out of work.</ref> Yet for the most part, other than during the periods of intense debate in the 1930s and 60s, the consensus in the 20th century among both professional economists and the general public remained that technology does not cause long-term joblessness.<ref>Woirol 1996, p. 3</ref>

21st century

Opinions

There is a prevailing opinion that we are in an era of technological unemployment – that technology is increasingly making skilled workers obsolete.

Prof. Mark MacCarthy (2014)<ref name="MacCarthy">MacCarthy, Mark (30 September 2014). "Time to kill the tech job-killing myth". The Hill. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref>

The general consensus that innovation does not cause long-term unemployment held strong for the first decade of the 21st century although it continued to be challenged by a number of academic works,<ref name = "Vivarelli2012"/><ref name = "Vivarelli2007"/> and by popular works such as Marshall Brain's Robotic Nation<ref name="Brain2003">Brain 2003.</ref> and Martin Ford's The Lights in the Tunnel: Automation, Accelerating Technology and the Economy of the Future.<ref name="Ford2009">Ford 2009.</ref>

Since the publication of their 2011 book Race Against the Machine, MIT professors Andrew McAfee and Erik Brynjolfsson have been prominent among those raising concern about technological unemployment. The two professors remain relatively optimistic, however, stating "the key to winning the race is not to compete against machines but to compete with machines".<ref name=NYTimesReview>Lohr, Steve (23 October 2011). "More Jobs Predicted for Machines, Not People". The New York Times.</ref><ref name=TechCrunch>Andrew Keen, Keen On How The Internet Is Making Us Both Richer and More Unequal (TCTV), interview with Andrew McAfee and Erik Brynjolfsson, TechCrunch, 2011.11.15</ref><ref name=BusinessInsider>Krasny, Jill (25 November 2011). "MIT Professors: The 99% Should Shake Their Fists At The Tech Boom". Business Insider.</ref><ref name=Salon-Timberg-2011>Timberg, Scott (18 December 2011). "The Clerk, RIP". Salon.com.</ref><ref name=Salon-Leonard-2014>Leonard, Andrew (17 January 2014). "Robots are stealing your job: How technology threatens to wipe out the middle class". Salon.com.</ref><ref>Rotman, David (June 2015). "How Technology Is Destroying Jobs". MIT. Archived from the original on 27 June 2015. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref><ref>"The FT's Summer books 2015" (Template:Registration required). Financial Times. 26 June 2015. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref>

Concern about technological unemployment grew in 2013 due in part to a number of studies predicting substantially increased technological unemployment in forthcoming decades and empirical evidence that, in certain sectors, employment is falling worldwide despite rising output, thus discounting globalization and offshoring as the only causes of increasing unemployment.<ref name = "replicants">Waters, Richard (3 March 2014). "Technology: Rise of the replicants" (Template:Registration required). Financial Times. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref><ref name="Martin">Carl Benedikt Frey & Michael A. Osborne (17 September 2013). "The future of employment: how susceptible are jobs to computerisation" (PDF). Oxford University, Oxford Martin School. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref><ref>Thompson, Derek (23 January 2014). "What Jobs Will the Robots Take?". The Nation. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref>

In 2013, professor Nick Bloom of Stanford University stated there had recently been a major change of heart concerning technological unemployment among his fellow economists.<ref>Special Report (29 March 2013). "A mighty contest: Job destruction by robots could outweigh creation". The Economist. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref> In 2014 the Financial Times reported that the impact of innovation on jobs has been a dominant theme in recent economic discussion.<ref name="control">Cardiff Garcia, Erik Brynjolfsson and Mariana Mazzucato (3 July 2014). Robots are still in our control (Template:Registration required). The Financial Times. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref> According to the academic and former politician Michael Ignatieff writing in 2014, questions concerning the effects of technological change have been "haunting democratic politics everywhere".<ref>Ignatieff, Michael (10 February 2014). "We need a new Bismarck to tame the machines" (Template:Registration required). Financial Times. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref> Concerns have included evidence showing worldwide falls in employment across sectors such as manufacturing; falls in pay for low and medium skilled workers stretching back several decades even as productivity continues to rise; the increase in often precarious platform mediated employment; and the occurrence of "jobless recoveries" after recent recessions. The 21st century has seen a variety of skilled tasks partially taken over by machines, including translation, legal research and even low level journalism. Care work, entertainment, and other tasks requiring empathy, previously thought safe from automation, have also begun to be performed by robots.<ref name = "replicants"/><ref name="Martin"/><ref>Lord Skidelsky (19 February 2013). "Rise of the robots: what will the future of work look like?". The Guardian. London. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref><ref> Bria, Francesca (February 2016). "The robot economy may already have arrived". openDemocracy. Retrieved 20 May 2016. </ref><ref>Srnicek, Nick (March 2016). "4 Reasons Why Technological Unemployment Might Really Be Different This Time". novara wire. Archived from the original on 25 June 2016. Retrieved 20 May 2016.</ref><ref> Andrew McAfee and Erik Brynjolfsson (2014). "passim, see esp Chpt. 9". The Second Machine Age: Work, Progress, and Prosperity in a Time of Brilliant Technologies. W. W. Norton & Company. ISBN 978-0393239355.</ref>

Former U.S. Treasury Secretary and Harvard economics professor Lawrence Summers stated in 2014 that he no longer believed automation would always create new jobs and that "This isn't some hypothetical future possibility. This is something that's emerging before us right now." Summers noted that already, more labor sectors were losing jobs than creating new ones.<ref group="note">Other recent statements by Summers include warnings on the "devastating consequences" for those who perform routine tasks arising from robots, 3-D printing, artificial intelligence, and similar technologies. In his view, "already there are more American men on disability insurance than doing production work in manufacturing. And the trends are all in the wrong direction, particularly for the less skilled, as the capacity of capital embodying artificial intelligence to replace white-collar as well as blue-collar work will increase rapidly in the years ahead." Summers has also said that "[T]here are many reasons to think the software revolution will be even more profound than the agricultural revolution. This time around, change will come faster and affect a much larger share of the economy. [...] [T]here are more sectors losing jobs than creating jobs. And the general-purpose aspect of software technology means that even the industries and jobs that it creates are not forever. [...] If current trends continue, it could well be that a generation from now a quarter of middle-aged men will be out of work at any given moment."</ref><ref name="summers">Lawrence H. Summers (7 July 2014). "Lawrence H. Summers on the Economic Challenge of the Future: Jobs". Archived from the original on 26 August 2014. Retrieved 22 August 2014.</ref><ref name=NYT-2014-12-15>Miller, Claire Cain (15 December 2014). "As Robots Grow Smarter, American Workers Struggle to Keep Up". The New York Times.</ref><ref name="inequalityPuzzle">Larry Summers, The Inequality Puzzle, Democracy: A Journal of Ideas, Issue #32, Spring 2014</ref><ref>Winick, Erin (12 December 2017). "Lawyer-bots are shaking up jobs". MIT Technology Review. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> While himself doubtful about technological unemployment, professor Mark MacCarthy stated in the fall of 2014 that it is now the "prevailing opinion" that the era of technological unemployment has arrived.<ref name="MacCarthy"/>

At the 2014 Davos meeting, Thomas Friedman reported that the link between technology and unemployment seemed to have been the dominant theme of that year's discussions. A survey at Davos 2014 found that 80% of 147 respondents agreed that technology was driving jobless growth.<ref>"Forum Debate: Rethinking Technology and Employment <--Centrality of work, 1:02 - 1:04 -->". World Economic Forum. January 2014. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref> At the 2015 Davos, Gillian Tett found that almost all delegates attending a discussion on inequality and technology expected an increase in inequality over the next five years, and gives the reason for this as the technological displacement of jobs.<ref>Gillian Tett (21 January 2015). technology would continue to displace jobs over the next five years (Template:Registration required). The Financial Times. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref> 2015 saw Martin Ford win the Financial Times and McKinsey Business Book of the Year Award for his Rise of the Robots: Technology and the Threat of a Jobless Future, and saw the first world summit on technological unemployment, held in New York. In late 2015, further warnings of potential worsening for technological unemployment came from Andy Haldane, the Bank of England's chief economist, and from Ignazio Visco, the governor of the Bank of Italy.<ref name = "Haldane2015">Haldane, Andy (November 2015). "Labour's Share". Bank of England. Archived from the original on 28 April 2016. Retrieved 20 May 2016.</ref><ref name = "Visco2015"> Visco, Ignazio (November 2015). "For the times they are a-changin'..." Bank of Italy. Retrieved 20 May 2016. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help) </ref> In an October 2016 interview, US President Barack Obama said that due to the growth of artificial intelligence, society would be debating "unconditional free money for everyone" within 10 to 20 years.<ref>"President Obama: We'll be debating unconditional free money 'over the next 10 or 20 years'". Business Insider. 12 October 2016. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> In 2019, computer scientist and artificial intelligence expert Stuart J. Russell stated that "in the long run nearly all current jobs will go away, so we need fairly radical policy changes to prepare for a very different future economy." In a book he authored, Russell claims that "One rapidly emerging picture is that of an economy where far fewer people work because work is unnecessary." However, he predicted that employment in healthcare, home care, and construction would increase.<ref>Zachary B. Wolf (24 August 2019). "The robots are coming for your job, too". CNN. illustrations by Max Pepper. Retrieved 8 September 2019.</ref>

Other economists[who?] have argued that long-term technological unemployment is unlikely. In 2014, Pew Research canvassed 1,896 technology professionals and economists and found a split of opinion: 48% of respondents believed that new technologies would displace more jobs than they would create by the year 2025, while 52% maintained that they would not.<ref>Smith, Aaron; Anderson, Janna (6 August 2014). "AI, Robotics, and the Future of Jobs". Pew Research Center. Retrieved 14 August 2014.</ref> Economics professor Bruce Chapman from Australian National University has advised that studies such as Frey and Osborne's tend to overstate the probability of future job losses, as they don't account for new employment likely to be created, due to technology, in what are currently unknown areas.<ref>Greber, Jacob (1 February 2015). "Employment fears in the face of increasing automation". The Australian Financial Review. Archived from the original on 4 January 2015. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref>

General public surveys have often found an expectation that automation would impact jobs widely, but not the jobs held by those particular people surveyed.<ref>Vincent, James (7 March 2018). "Most Americans think artificial intelligence will destroy other people's jobs, not theirs". The Verge.</ref>

Studies

A number of studies have predicted that automation will take a large proportion of jobs in the future, but estimates of the level of unemployment this will cause vary. Research by Carl Benedikt Frey and Michael Osborne of the Oxford Martin School showed that employees engaged in "tasks following well-defined procedures that can easily be performed by sophisticated algorithms" are at risk of displacement. The study, published in 2013, shows that automation can affect both skilled and unskilled work and both high and low-paying occupations; however, low-paid physical occupations are most at risk. It estimated that 47% of US jobs were at high risk of automation.<ref name="Martin"/> In 2014, the economic think tank Bruegel released a study, based on the Frey and Osborne approach, claiming that across the European Union's 28 member states, 54% of jobs were at risk of automation. The countries where jobs were least vulnerable to automation were Sweden, with 46.69% of jobs vulnerable, the UK at 47.17%, the Netherlands at 49.50%, and France and Denmark, both at 49.54%. The countries where jobs were found to be most vulnerable were Romania at 61.93%, Portugal at 58.94%, Croatia at 57.9%, and Bulgaria at 56.56%.<ref>"More than 50% of EU jobs at risk of computerisation". 22 July 2014. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref><ref>Bowles, Jeremy (22 July 2014). "Over Half of EU Jobs Could Be Replaced By Computers". Business Insider. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> A 2015 report by the Taub Center found that 41% of jobs in Israel were at risk of being automated within the next two decades.<ref>Madhala-Brik, Shavit. "Occupations at Risk: Computerization Trends in the Israeli Labor Market" (PDF). taubcenter.org.il. Archived from the original (PDF) on 18 November 2017. Retrieved 14 August 2017.</ref> In January 2016, a joint study by the Oxford Martin School and Citibank, based on previous studies on automation and data from the World Bank, found that the risk of automation in developing countries was much higher than in developed countries. It found that 77% of jobs in China, 69% of jobs in India, 85% of jobs in Ethiopia, and 55% of jobs in Uzbekistan were at risk of automation.<ref>"Impact of automation on developing countries puts up to 85% of jobs at risk". Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> The World Bank similarly employed the methodology of Frey and Osborne. A 2016 study by the International Labour Organization found 74% of salaried electrical & electronics industry positions in Thailand, 75% of salaried electrical & electronics industry positions in Vietnam, 63% of salaried electrical & electronics industry positions in Indonesia, and 81% of salaried electrical & electronics industry positions in the Philippines were at high risk of automation.<ref>"Bureau for Employers' Activities" (PDF). Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> A 2016 United Nations report stated that 75% of jobs in the developing world were at risk of automation, and predicted that more jobs might be lost when corporations stop outsourcing to developing countries after automation in industrialized countries makes it less lucrative to outsource to countries with lower labor costs.<ref>"UN Report: Robots Will Replace Two-Thirds of All Workers in the Developing World". 11 November 2016. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref>

The Council of Economic Advisers, a US government agency tasked with providing economic research for the White House, in the 2016 Economic Report of the President, used the data from the Frey and Osborne study to estimate that 83% of jobs with an hourly wage below $20, 31% of jobs with an hourly wage between $20 and $40, and 4% of jobs with an hourly wage above $40 were at risk of automation.<ref>Goldstein, Steve (23 February 2016). "The robots are coming for jobs that pay $20 an hour or less, White House finds". MarketWatch. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> A 2016 study by Ryerson University (now Toronto Metropolitan University) found that 42% of jobs in Canada were at risk of automation, dividing them into two categories - "high risk" jobs and "low risk" jobs. High risk jobs were mainly lower-income jobs that required lower education levels than average. Low risk jobs were on average more skilled positions. The report found a 70% chance that high risk jobs and a 30% chance that low risk jobs would be affected by automation in the next 10–20 years.<ref>"Automation could put 4 in 10 Canadian jobs at high risk in future, study says". CBC News. 15 June 2016. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> A 2017 study by PricewaterhouseCoopers found that up to 38% of jobs in the US, 35% of jobs in Germany, 30% of jobs in the UK, and 21% of jobs in Japan were at high risk of being automated by the early 2030s.<ref>Nelson, Eshe (24 March 2017). "Why American jobs are more at risk of automation than jobs in Germany or the UK". Quartz. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> A 2017 study by Ball State University found about half of American jobs were at risk of automation, many of them low-income jobs.<ref>Wells, Nick (19 July 2017). "Half of American jobs are at risk from automation, new study suggests". CNBC. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> A September 2017 report by McKinsey & Company found that as of 2015, 478 billion out of 749 billion working hours per year dedicated to manufacturing, or $2.7 trillion out of $5.1 trillion in labor, were already automatable. In low-skill areas, 82% of labor in apparel goods, 80% of agriculture processing, 76% of food manufacturing, and 60% of beverage manufacturing were subject to automation. In mid-skill areas, 72% of basic materials production and 70% of furniture manufacturing was automatable. In high-skill areas, 52% of aerospace and defense labor and 50% of advanced electronics labor could be automated.<ref>Bolden-Barrett, Valerie (13 September 2017). "Report: Majority of manufacturing jobs could be automated". HR Dive. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> In October 2017, a survey of information technology decision makers in the US and UK found that a majority believed that most business processes could be automated by 2022. On average, they said that 59% of business processes were subject to automation.<ref>"IT Decision Makers Speak: 59% of Business Processes Could Be Automated by 2022". Business Wire. 4 October 2017. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> A November 2017 report by the McKinsey Global Institute that analyzed around 800 occupations in 46 countries estimated that between 400 million and 800 million jobs could be lost due to robotic automation by 2030. It estimated that jobs were more at risk in developed countries than developing countries due to a greater availability of capital to invest in automation.<ref>"What the future of work will mean for jobs, skills, and wages". McKinsey & Company. 28 November 2017. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> Job losses and downward mobility blamed on automation has been cited as one of many factors in the resurgence of nationalist and protectionist politics in the US, UK and France, among other countries.<ref>Dashevsky, Evan (8 November 2017). "How Robots Caused Brexit and the Rise of Donald Trump". PC Magazine. Archived from the original on 8 November 2017. Retrieved 11 January 2018.</ref><ref>Torrance, Jack (25 July 2017). "Robots for Trump: Did automation swing the US election?". Management Today. Retrieved 11 January 2018.</ref><ref>Harris, John (29 December 2016). "The lesson of Trump and Brexit: a society too complex for its people risks everything". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 11 January 2018.</ref><ref>West, Darrell (18 April 2018). "Will robots and AI take your job? The economic and political consequences of automation". Brookings Institution.</ref><ref>Byrne, Clare (7 December 2016). "'People are lost': Voters in France's 'Trumplands' look to far right". The Local.fr.</ref>

However, not all recent empirical studies have found evidence to support the idea that automation will cause widespread unemployment. A study released in 2015, examining the impact of industrial robots in 17 countries between 1993 and 2007, found no overall reduction in employment was caused by the robots, and that there was a slight increase in overall wages.<ref name = "GGG">Graetz, Georg; Michaels, Guy (March 2015). "Robots at Work". Centre for Economic Policy Research. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref> According to a study published in McKinsey Quarterly<ref name=MKQ1115>Michael Chui, James Manyika, and Mehdi Miremadi (November 2015). "Four fundamentals of workplace automation As the automation of physical and knowledge work advances, many jobs will be redefined rather than eliminated—at least in the short term". McKinsey Quarterly. Archived from the original on 7 November 2015. Retrieved 7 November 2015. Very few occupations will be automated in their entirety in the near or medium term. Rather, certain activities are more likely to be automated....{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)</ref> in 2015 the impact of computerization in most cases is not replacement of employees but automation of portions of the tasks they perform.<ref name=NYT11615>Lohr, Steve (6 November 2015). "Automation Will Change Jobs More Than Kill Them". The New York Times. Retrieved 7 November 2015. technology-driven automation will affect most every occupation and can change work, according to new research from McKinsey</ref> A 2016 OECD study found that among the 21 OECD countries surveyed, on average only 9% of jobs were in foreseeable danger of automation, but this varied greatly among countries: for example in South Korea the figure of at-risk jobs was 6% while in Austria it was 12%.<ref>Arntz, Melanie; Gregory, Terry; Zierahn, Ulrich (14 May 2016). "The Risk of Automation for Jobs in OECD Countries". OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers. doi:10.1787/5jlz9h56dvq7-en. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> In contrast to other studies, the OECD study does not primarily base its assessment on the tasks that a job entails, but also includes demographic variables, including sex, education and age. It is not clear however why a job should be more or less automatise just because it is performed by a woman. In 2017, Forrester estimated that automation would result in a net loss of about 7% of jobs in the US by 2027, replacing 17% of jobs while creating new jobs equivalent to 10% of the workforce.<ref>"Forrester : Marketing : Forrester Predicts Automation Will Displace 24.7 Million Jobs And Add 14.9 Million Jobs By 2027". www.forrester.com. Archived from the original on 4 April 2018. Retrieved 14 March 2018.</ref> Another study argued that the risk of US jobs to automation had been overestimated due to factors such as the heterogeneity of tasks within occupations and the adaptability of jobs being neglected. The study found that once this was taken into account, the number of occupations at risk to automation in the US drops, ceteris paribus, from 38% to 9%.<ref>Arntz, Melanie; Gregory, Terry; Zierahn, Ulrich. "Revisiting the Risk of Automation". Retrieved 6 November 2017.</ref> A 2017 study on the effect of automation on Germany found no evidence that automation caused total job losses but that they do effect the jobs people are employed in; losses in the industrial sector due to automation were offset by gains in the service sector. Manufacturing workers were also not at risk from automation and were in fact more likely to remain employed, though not necessarily doing the same tasks. However, automation did result in a decrease in labour's income share as it raised productivity but not wages.<ref>Template:Cite SSRN</ref>

A 2018 Brookings Institution study that analyzed 28 industries in 18 OECD countries from 1970 to 2018 found that automation was responsible for holding down wages. Although it concluded that automation did not reduce the overall number of jobs available and even increased them, it found that from the 1970s to the 2010s, it had reduced the share of human labor in the value added to the work, and thus had helped to slow wage growth.<ref>Autor, David; Salomons, Anna (8 March 2018). "Is automation labor-displacing? Productivity growth, employment, and the labor share". Brookings.</ref> In April 2018, Adair Turner, former Chairman of the Financial Services Authority and head of the Institute for New Economic Thinking, stated that it would already be possible to automate 50% of jobs with current technology, and that it will be possible to automate all jobs by 2060.<ref>Kook, Anna (12 April 2018). "Half of all jobs can today be automated – and within 50 years, all of them can be". MarketWatch.</ref>

Premature deindustrialization

Premature deindustrialization occurs when developing nations deindustrialize without first becoming rich, as happened with the advanced economies. The concept was popularized by Dani Rodrik in 2013, who went on to publish several papers showing the growing empirical evidence for the phenomena. Premature deindustrialization adds to concern over technological unemployment for developing countries - as traditional compensation effects that advanced economy workers enjoyed, such being able to get well paid work in the service sector after losing their factory jobs - may not be available.<ref>Matthew Yglesias (2016). "Premature deindustrialization: the new threat to global economic development". vox.com. Retrieved 22 March 2020.</ref><ref> Joshua Greenstein (2019). "Development Without Industrialization? Household Well-Being and Premature Deindustrialization". Journal of Economic Issues. 55 (3): 612–633. doi:10.1080/00213624.2019.1634452. S2CID 202310084. </ref> Some commentators, such as Carl Benedikt Frey, argue that with the right responses, the negative effects of further automation on workers in developing economies can still be avoided. <ref>Carl Benedikt Frey, Ebrahim Rahbari (2016). "Do labor saving technologies spell the death of jobs in the developing world?" (PDF). Brookings Institution. Retrieved 22 March 2020.</ref>

Artificial intelligence

Since about 2017, a new wave of concern over technological unemployment had become prominent, this time over the effects of artificial intelligence (AI).<ref> "Artificial intelligence will create new kinds of work". The Economist. 26 August 2017. Retrieved 22 March 2020. </ref> Commentators including Calum Chace and Daniel Hulme have warned that if unchecked, AI threatens to cause an "economic singularity", with job churn too rapid for humans to adapt to, leading to widespread technological unemployment. Though they also advise that with the right responses by business leaders, policy makers and society, the impact of AI could be a net positive for workers.<ref> Calum Chace (2016). "Proclamation, Anniversary". The Economic Singularity: Artificial intelligence and the death of capitalism. Three Cs. ISBN 978-0993211645.</ref><ref> Calum Chace, Daniel Hulme (2016). "passim". Stories from 2045. Three Cs. ISBN 978-0993211645.</ref>

Morgan R. Frank et al. cautions that there are several barriers preventing researchers from making accurate predictions of the effects AI will have on future job markets.<ref>Frank, Morgan R.; Autor, David; Bessen, James E.; Brynjolfsson, Erik; Cebrian, Manuel; Deming, David J.; Feldman, Maryann; Groh, Matthew; Lobo, José; Moro, Esteban; Wang, Dashun (2 April 2019). "Toward understanding the impact of artificial intelligence on labor". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 116 (14): 6531–6539. doi:10.1073/pnas.1900949116. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 6452673. PMID 30910965.</ref> Marian Krakovsky has argued that the jobs most likely to be completely replaced by AI are in middle-class areas, such as professional services. Often, the practical solution is to find another job, but workers may not have the qualifications for high-level jobs and so must drop to lower level jobs. However, Krakovsky (2018) predicts that AI will largely take the route of "complementing people," rather than "replicating people." Suggesting that the goal of people implementing AI is to improve the life of workers, not replace them.<ref>Krakovsky, Marina (27 December 2017). "The new jobs". Communications of the ACM. 61 (1): 21–23. doi:10.1145/3157077. ISSN 0001-0782. S2CID 1085217.</ref> Studies have also shown that rather than solely destroying jobs AI can also create work: albeit low-skill jobs to train AI in low-income countries.<ref>Anwar, Mohammad Amir; Graham, Mark (20 April 2020). "Digital labour at economic margins: African workers and the global information economy". Review of African Political Economy. 47 (163): 95–105. doi:10.1080/03056244.2020.1728243. ISSN 0305-6244. S2CID 214074400.</ref>

Following President Putin's 2017 statement that which ever country first achieves mastery in AI "will become the ruler of the world", various national and supranational governments have announced AI strategies. Concerns on not falling behind in the AI arms race have been more prominent than worries over AI's potential to cause unemployment. Several strategies suggest that achieving a leading role in AI should help their citizens get more rewarding jobs. Finland has aimed to help the citizens of other EU nations acquire the skills they need to compete in the post AI jobs market, making a free course on "The Elements of AI" available in multiple European languages.<ref>Gregory C. Allen (5 September 2017). "Putin and Musk are right: Whoever masters AI will run the world". CNN. Retrieved 22 March 2020.</ref><ref>Tim Dutton (28 June 2018). "An Overview of National AI Strategies". Medium.com. Retrieved 22 March 2020.</ref><ref>Olli Koski, Kai Husso (20 June 2018). "Artificial Intelligence: Four Perspectives on the Economy, Employment, Knowledge and Ethics". Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment (Finland) (in svenska). Retrieved 22 March 2020.</ref> Oracle CEO Mark Hurd predicted that AI "will actually create more jobs, not less jobs" as humans will be needed to manage AI systems.<ref>"Oracle CEO Mark Hurd sees no reason to fear ERP AI". SearchERP. Archived from the original on 6 May 2019. Retrieved 6 May 2019.</ref>

Martin Ford argues that many jobs are routine, repetitive and (to an AI) predictable; Ford warns that these jobs may be automated in the next couple of decades, and that many of the new jobs may not be "accessible to people with average capability", even with retraining.<ref name="FOOTNOTEFordColvin2015">Ford & Colvin 2015.</ref>

Certain digital technologies are predicted to result in more job losses than others. For example, in recent years, the adoption of modern robotics has led to net employment growth. However, many businesses anticipate that automation, or employing robots would result in job losses in the future. This is especially true for companies in Central and Eastern Europe.<ref name=":34">Bank, European Investment (5 May 2022). Digitalisation in Europe 2021-2022: Evidence from the EIB Investment Survey. European Investment Bank. ISBN 978-92-861-5233-7.</ref><ref>Parschau, Christian; Hauge, Jostein (1 October 2020). "Is automation stealing manufacturing jobs? Evidence from South Africa's apparel industry". Geoforum. 115: 120–131. doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2020.07.002. ISSN 0016-7185. S2CID 224877507.</ref><ref name="Genz">Genz, Sabrina (5 May 2022). "The nuanced relationship between cutting-edge technologies and jobs: Evidence from Germany". Brookings. Retrieved 5 June 2022.</ref>

Other digital technologies, such as platforms or big data, are projected to have a more neutral impact on employment.<ref name=":34" /><ref name="Genz"/>

Issues within the debates

Long-term effects on employment

There are more sectors losing jobs than creating jobs. And the general-purpose aspect of software technology means that even the industries and jobs that it creates are not forever.

Lawrence Summers<ref name="summers" />

Participants in the technological employment debates agree that temporary job losses can result from technological innovation. Similarly, there is no dispute that innovation sometimes has positive effects on workers. Disagreement focuses on whether it is possible for innovation to have a lasting negative impact on overall employment. Levels of persistent unemployment can be quantified empirically, but the causes are subject to debate. Optimists accept short term unemployment may be caused by innovation, yet claim that after a while, compensation effects will always create at least as many jobs as were originally destroyed. While this optimistic view has been continually challenged, it was dominant among mainstream economists for most of the 19th and 20th centuries.<ref name="Woirol 1996 loc= pp. 77 - 90">Woirol 1996, pp. 77–90</ref><ref name = "sympathy"/> For example, labor economists Jacob Mincer and Stephan Danninger developed an empirical study using data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, and find that although in the short run, technological progress seems to have unclear effects on aggregate unemployment, it reduces unemployment in the long run. When they include a 5-year lag, however, the evidence supporting a short-run employment effect of technology seems to disappear as well, suggesting that technological unemployment "appears to be a myth".<ref>Mincer, Jacob; Danninger, Stephan (July 2000). "Technology, Unemployment, and Inflation" (PDF). National Bureau of Economic Research.</ref> Other studies, on the other hand, suggest that the labour-market effects of technologies such as industrial robots strongly depend on domestic institutional context.<ref>Van Overbeke, Toon (2022). "Conflict or cooperation? Exploring the relationship between cooperative institutions and robotisation". British Journal of Industrial Relations. 61 (3): 550–573. doi:10.1111/bjir.12719.</ref>

The concept of structural unemployment, a lasting level of joblessness that does not disappear even at the high point of the business cycle, became popular in the 1960s. For pessimists, technological unemployment is one of the factors driving the wider phenomena of structural unemployment. Since the 1980s, even optimistic economists have increasingly accepted that structural unemployment has indeed risen in advanced economies, but they have tended to attribute this on globalisation and offshoring rather than technological change.[citation needed] Others claim a chief cause of the lasting increase in unemployment has been the reluctance of governments to pursue expansionary policies since the displacement of Keynesianism that occurred in the 1970s and early 80s.<ref name="Woirol 1996 loc= pp. 77 - 90"/><ref name="Effective Demand"/><ref name = "Vivarelli2012"/> In the 21st century, and especially since 2013, pessimists have been arguing with increasing frequency that lasting worldwide technological unemployment is a growing threat.<ref name = "sympathy"/><ref name = "replicants"/><ref name="Martin"/><ref>On the other hand, from a more positive perspective, some have argued that technological change will alter the structure of an organization in the sense that those in management roles will increasingly become more specialized to those roles as technology that assists collaboration and workflow management allows employees to manage themselves. The typical management role will, as a result, change to allow managers to concentrate on the task of supporting employees and improving their performance thus allowing them to add more, rather than less, value.</ref>

Compensation effects

John Kay inventor of the Fly Shuttle AD 1753, by Ford Madox Brown, depicting the inventor John Kay kissing his wife goodbye as men carry him away from his home to escape a mob angry about his labour-saving mechanical loom. Compensation effects were not widely understood at this time.

Compensation effects are labour-friendly consequences of innovation which "compensate" workers for job losses initially caused by new technology. In the 1820s, several compensation effects were described by Jean-Baptiste Say in response to Ricardo's statement that long-term technological unemployment could occur. Soon after, a whole system of effects was developed by Ramsey McCulloch. The system was labelled "compensation theory" by Karl Marx, who criticized its ideas, arguing that none of the effects were guaranteed to operate. Disagreement over the effectiveness of compensation effects has remained a central part of academic debates on technological unemployment ever since.<ref name = "Vivarelli2012"/><ref name="Blaug 1997 loc= p182">Blaug 1997, p182</ref>

Compensation effects include:

  1. By new machines. (The labour needed to build the new equipment that applied innovation requires.)
  2. By new investments. (Enabled by the cost savings and therefore increased profits from the new technology.)
  3. By changes in wages. (In cases where unemployment does occur, this can cause a lowering of wages, thus allowing more workers to be re-employed at the now lower cost. On the other hand, sometimes workers will enjoy wage increases as their profitability rises. This leads to increased income and therefore increased spending, which in turn encourages job creation.)
  4. By lower prices. (Which then lead to more demand, and therefore more employment.) Lower prices can also help offset wage cuts, as cheaper goods will increase workers' buying power.
  5. By new products. (Where innovation directly creates new jobs.)

The "by new machines" effect is now rarely discussed by economists; it is often accepted that Marx successfully refuted it.<ref name = "Vivarelli2012"/> Even pessimists often concede that product innovation associated with the "by new products" effect can sometimes have a positive effect on employment. An important distinction can be drawn between 'process' and 'product' innovations.<ref group="note">Labour-displacing technologies can be classified under the headings of mechanization, automation, and process improvement. The first two fundamentally involve transferring tasks from humans to machines. The third often involves the elimination of tasks altogether. The common theme of all three is that tasks are removed from the workforce, decreasing employment. In practice, the categories often overlap: a process improvement can include an automating or mechanizing achievement. The line between mechanization and automation is also subjective, as sometimes mechanization can involve sufficient control to be viewed as part of automation.</ref> Evidence from Latin America seems to suggest that product innovation significantly contributes to the employment growth at the firm level, more so than process innovation.<ref>Crespi, Gustavo; Tacsir, Ezequiel (December 2012). "Effects of Innovation on Employment in Latin America". Inter-American Development Bank.</ref> The extent to which the other effects are successful in compensating the workforce for job losses has been extensively debated throughout the history of modern economics; the issue is still not resolved.<ref name = "Vivarelli2012"> Vivarelli, Marco (January 2012). "Innovation, Employment and Skills in Advanced and Developing Countries: A Survey of the Literature" (PDF). Institute for the Study of Labor. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref><ref name = "Vivarelli2007"> Vivarelli, Marco (February 2007). "Innovation and Employment: : A Survey" (PDF). Institute for the Study of Labor. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref> One such effect that potentially complements the compensation effect is job multiplier. According to research developed by Enrico Moretti, with each additional skilled job created in high tech industries in a given city, more than two jobs are created in the non-tradable sector. His findings suggest that technological growth and the resulting job-creation in high-tech industries might have a more significant spillover effect than anticipated.<ref>Moretti, Enrico (May 2010). "Local Multipliers". American Economic Review. 100 (2): 373–377. doi:10.1257/aer.100.2.373.</ref> Evidence from Europe also supports such a job multiplier effect, showing local high-tech jobs could create five additional low-tech jobs.<ref>Goos, Maarten; Konings, Jozef; Vandeweyer, Marieke (September 2015). "Employment Growth in Europe: The Roles of Innovation, Local Job Multipliers and Institutions". Tjalling C. Koopmans Research Institute.</ref>

Many economists pessimistic about technological unemployment accept that compensation effects did largely operate as the optimists claimed through most of the 19th and 20th century. Yet they hold that the advent of computerisation means that compensation effects have become less effective. An early example of this argument was made by Wassily Leontief in 1983. He conceded that after some disruption, the advance of mechanization during the Industrial Revolution increased the demand for labour as well as increasing pay due to effects that flow from increased productivity.<ref name="Advance" /> While early machines lowered the demand for muscle power, they were unintelligent and needed large numbers of human operators to remain productive. Yet since the introduction of computers into the workplace, there is now less need not just for muscle power but also for human brain power. Hence even as productivity continues to rise, the lower demand for human labour may mean less pay and employment.<ref name = "Vivarelli2012"/><ref name="Martin"/>

Luddite fallacy

If the Luddite fallacy were true we would all be out of work because productivity has been increasing for two centuries.

Alex Tabarrok<ref name="Tabarrok">Tabarrok, Alex (31 December 2003). "Productivity and unemployment". Marginal Revolution. Retrieved 11 March 2007.</ref>

The term "Luddite fallacy" is sometimes used to express the view that those concerned about long-term technological unemployment are committing a fallacy, as they fail to account for compensation effects. People who use the term typically expect that technological progress will have no long-term impact on employment levels, and eventually will raise wages for all workers, because progress helps to increase the overall wealth of society. The term is originating on from the Luddites, members of an early 19th century English anti-textile-machinery organisation. During the 20th century and the first decade of the 21st century, the dominant view among economists has been that belief in long-term technological unemployment was indeed a fallacy. More recently, there has been increased support for the view that the benefits of automation are not equally distributed.<ref name = "sympathy"> Krugman, Paul (12 June 2013). "Sympathy for the Luddites". The New York Times. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref><ref>Ford 2009, Chpt 3, 'The Luddite Fallacy'</ref><ref name = "Death">Lord Skidelsky (12 June 2013). "Death to Machines?". Project Syndicate. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref>

There are two different theories for why long-term difficulty could develop.

  1. Traditionally ascribed to the Luddites (accurately or not), that there is a finite amount of work available and if machines do it, there can be none left for humans. Economists may call this the lump of labour fallacy, arguing that in reality no such limitation exists.
  2. A long-term difficulty can arise that has nothing to do with any lump of labour. In this view, the amount of work that can exist is infinite, but
  • machines can do most of the "easy" work that requires less skill, talent, knowledge, or insight
  • the definition of what is "easy" expands as information technology progresses, and
  • the work that lies beyond "easy" may require greater brainpower than most people have.

This second view is supported by many modern advocates of the possibility of long-term, systemic technological unemployment.

Skill levels and technological unemployment

A frequent view among those discussing the effect of innovation on the labour market has been that it mainly hurts those with low skills, while often benefiting skilled workers. According to scholars such as Lawrence F. Katz, this may have been true for much of the twentieth century, yet in the 19th century, innovations in the workplace largely displaced costly skilled artisans, and generally benefited the low skilled. While 21st century innovation has been replacing some unskilled work, other low skilled occupations remain resistant to automation, while white collar work requiring intermediate skills is increasingly being performed by autonomous computer programs.<ref name = "relative">Katz, Lawrence F.; Margo, Robert A. (2014). "Technical Change and the Relative Demand for Skilled Labor: The United States in Historical Perspective". In Boustan; Frydman; Margo (eds.). Human Capital in History: The American Record. doi:10.3386/w18752. S2CID 41004800.</ref><ref name = "polarization"> David H. Autor; Dorn, David (August 2013). "The growth of low skill service jobs and the polarization of the US labor market". The American Economic Review. 103 (5): 1553–97. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.231.4843. doi:10.1257/aer.103.5.1553. S2CID 844385. </ref><ref name="Reversal">Beaudry, Paul; Green, David A.; Sand, Benjamin M. (2016). "The Great Reversal in the Demand for Skill and Cognitive Tasks" (PDF). Journal of Labor Economics. 34 (S1): S199–S247. doi:10.1086/682347. S2CID 36722085.</ref>

Some recent studies however, such as a 2015 paper by Georg Graetz and Guy Michaels, found that at least in the area they studied – the impact of industrial robots – innovation is boosting pay for highly skilled workers while having a more negative impact on those with low to medium skills.<ref name="GGG" /> A 2015 report by Carl Benedikt Frey, Michael Osborne and Citi Research agreed that innovation had been disruptive mostly to middle-skilled jobs, yet predicted that in the next ten years the impact of automation would fall most heavily on those with low skills.<ref name = "OM2015"> Carl Benedikt Frey, Michael Osborne and Citi Research (February 2015). "TECHNOLOGY AT WORK : The Future of Innovation and Employment" (PDF). Oxford Martin School. Retrieved 4 November 2015. </ref>

Geoffrey Colvin at Forbes argued that predictions on the kind of work a computer will never be able to do have proven inaccurate. A better approach to anticipate the skills on which humans will provide value would be to find out activities where we will insist that humans remain accountable for important decisions, such as with judges, CEOs, bus drivers and government leaders, or where human nature can only be satisfied by deep interpersonal connections, even if those tasks could be automated.<ref>Colvin, Geoff (23 July 2015). "Humans are underrated". Fortune. Retrieved 26 July 2015.</ref>

In contrast, others see even skilled human laborers being obsolete. Oxford academics Carl Benedikt Frey and Michael A Osborne have predicted computerization could make nearly half of jobs redundant;<ref>Meltzer, Tom (15 June 2014). "Robot doctors online lawyers automated architects: the future of the professions?". The Guardian.</ref> of the 702 professions assessed, they found a strong correlation between education and income with ability to be automated, with office jobs and service work being some of the more at risk.<ref>Frey, Carl Benedikt; Osborne, Michael A. (17 September 2013). "The future of employment: How susceptible are jobs to computerization?" (PDF).</ref> In 2012 co-founder of Sun Microsystems Vinod Khosla predicted that 80% of medical doctors' jobs would be lost in the next two decades to automated machine learning medical diagnostic software.<ref>Khosla, Vonod (10 January 2012). "Do We Need Doctors or Algorithms?". TechCrunch.</ref>

The issue of redundant job places is elaborated by the 2019 paper by Natalya Kozlova, according to which over 50% of workers in Russia perform work that requires low levels of education and can be replaced by applying digital technologies. Only 13% of those people possess education that exceeds the level of intellectual computer systems present today and expected within the following decade.<ref>Козлова, Наталья Шумафовна (2019). "Цифровые технологии в образовании". Вестник Майкопского Государственного Технологического Университета (in русский) (1). doi:10.24411/2078-1024-2019-11008. ISSN 2078-1024.</ref>

Empirical findings

There has been a significant amount of empirical research that attempts to quantify the impact of technological unemployment, mainly at the microeconomic level. Most existing firm-level research has found a labor-friendly nature of technological innovations. For example, German economists Stefan Lachenmaier and Horst Rottmann find that both product and process innovation have a positive effect on employment. They also find that process innovation has a more significant job creation effect than product innovation.<ref>Lachenmaier, Stefan; Rottmann, Horst (2011). "May 2010". International Journal of Industrial Organization. 29 (2): 210–220. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.522.7577. doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2010.05.004. S2CID 56406443.</ref> This result is supported by evidence in the United States as well, which shows that manufacturing firm innovations have a positive effect on the total number of jobs, not just limited to firm-specific behavior.<ref>Coad, Alex; Rao, Rekha (May 2011). "The firm-level employment effects of innovations in high-tech US manufacturing industries". Journal of Evolutionary Economics. 21 (2): 255–283. doi:10.1007/s00191-010-0209-x. S2CID 154768766.</ref>

At the industry level, however, researchers have found mixed results with regard to the employment effect of technological changes. A 2017 study on manufacturing and service sectors in 11 European countries suggests that positive employment effects of technological innovations only exist in the medium- and high-tech sectors. There also seems to be a negative correlation between employment and capital formation, which suggests that technological progress could potentially be labor-saving given that process innovation is often incorporated in investment.<ref>Piva, Mariacristina; Vivarelli, Marco (January 2017). "Technological Change and Employment: Were Ricardo and Marx Right?". IZA Institute of Labor Economics.</ref>

Limited macroeconomic analysis has been done to study the relationship between technological shocks and unemployment. The small amount of existing research, however, suggests mixed results. Italian economist Marco Vivarelli finds that the labor-saving effect of process innovation appears to have affected the Italian economy more negatively than the United States. On the other hand, the job creating effect of product innovation could only be observed in the United States, not Italy.<ref>Vivarelli, Marco (1995). The Economics of Technology and Employment Theory and Empirical Evidence. Italy: Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN 978-1-85898-166-6.</ref> Another study in 2013 finds a more transitory, rather than permanent, unemployment effect of technological change.<ref>Feldmann, Horst (November 2013). "Technological unemployment in industrial countries". Journal of Evolutionary Economics. 23 (5): 1099–1126. doi:10.1007/s00191-013-0308-6. S2CID 154073397.</ref>

Measures of technological innovation

There have been four main approaches that attempt to capture and document technological innovation quantitatively.[citation needed] The first one, proposed by Jordi Gali in 1999 and further developed by Neville Francis and Valerie A. Ramey in 2005, is to use long-run restrictions in a vector autoregression (VAR) to identify technological shocks, assuming that only technology affects long-run productivity.<ref>Gali, Jordi (1999). "Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations?" (PDF). American Economic Review. 89 (1): 249–271. doi:10.1257/aer.89.1.249. S2CID 154622671.</ref><ref>Francis, Neville; Ramey, Valerie (2005). "Is the Technology-Driven Real Business Cycle Hypothesis Dead? Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations Revisited". Journal of Monetary Economics. 52 (8): 1379–1399. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.198.157. doi:10.1016/j.jmoneco.2004.08.009.</ref>

The second approach is from Susanto Basu, John Fernald and Miles Kimball.<ref>Basu, Susanto; Fernald, John; Kimball, Miles (2006). "Are Technology Improvements Contractionary?". American Economic Review. 96 (5): 1418–48. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.202.121. doi:10.1257/aer.96.5.1418. S2CID 55596760.</ref> They create a measure of aggregate technology change with augmented Solow residuals, controlling for aggregate, non-technological effects such as non-constant returns and imperfect competition.

The third method, initially developed by John Shea in 1999, takes a more direct approach and employs observable indicators such as research and development (R&D) spending, and number of patent applications.<ref>Shea, John (1998). "What Do Technology Shocks Do?" (PDF). NBER Macroeconomics Annual. 13: 275–322. doi:10.1086/ma.13.4623748. S2CID 152644849.</ref> This measure of technological innovation is widely used in empirical research, since it does not rely on the assumption that only technology affects long-run productivity, and fairly accurately captures output variation based on input variation. However, there are limitations with direct measures such as R&D. For example, since R&D only measures the input in innovation, the output is unlikely to be perfectly correlated with the input. In addition, R&D fails to capture the indeterminate lag between developing a new product or service, and bringing it to market.<ref>Alexopoulos, Michelle; Cohen, Jon (2011). "Volumes of evidence: examining technical change in the last century through a new lens" (PDF). Canadian Journal of Economics. 44 (2): 413–450. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5982.2011.01639.x. S2CID 153779555.</ref>

The fourth approach, constructed by Michelle Alexopoulos, looks at the number of new titles published in the fields of technology and computer science to reflect technological progress, which he found to be consistent with R&D expenditure data.<ref>Alexopoulos, Michelle (2011). "Read All about It!! What Happens Following a Technology Shock?" (PDF). American Economic Review. 101 (4): 1144–1179. doi:10.1257/aer.101.4.1144. S2CID 154653527.</ref> Compared with R&D, this indicator captures the lag between changes in technology.

Solutions

Preventing net job losses

Banning/refusing innovation

"What I object to, is the craze for machinery, not machinery as such. The craze is for what they call labour-saving machinery. Men go on 'saving labour', till thousands are without work and thrown on the open streets to die of starvation." — Gandhi, 1924<ref>For a small collection of quotes by Gandhi relating to his view that innovation should be slowed while unemployment exists see The place of machines</ref>

Historically, innovations were sometimes banned due to concerns about their impact on employment. Since the development of modern economics, however, this option has generally not even been considered as a solution, at least not for the advanced economies. Even commentators who are pessimistic about long-term technological unemployment invariably consider innovation to be an overall benefit to society, with J. S. Mill being perhaps the only prominent western political economist to have suggested prohibiting the use of technology as a possible solution to unemployment.<ref name="Blaug 1997 loc= p182"/>

Gandhian economics called for a delay in the uptake of labour saving machines until unemployment was alleviated, however this advice was largely rejected by Nehru who was to become prime minister once India achieved its independence. The policy of slowing the introduction of innovation so as to avoid technological unemployment was, however, implemented in the 20th century within China under Mao's administration.<ref> B. N. Ghosh (2007). Gandhian political economy: principles, practice and policy. Ashgate. pp. 14, 15. ISBN 978-0754646815.</ref><ref> Sanghvi, Vijay (2006). Congress Resurgence Under Sonia Gandhi. Kalpaz. pp. 33–35. ISBN 978-8178353401.</ref><ref> Ram K. Vepa (2003). Mao's China: A Nation in Transition. Abhinav Publications. pp. 180–183. ISBN 978-8170171119.</ref>

Shorter working hours

In 1870, the average American worker clocked up about 75 hours per week. Just prior to World War II working hours had fallen to about 42 per week, and the fall was similar in other advanced economies. According to Wassily Leontief, this was a voluntary increase in technological unemployment. The reduction in working hours helped share out available work, and was favoured by workers who were happy to reduce hours to gain extra leisure, as innovation was at the time generally helping to increase their rates of pay.<ref name = "Advance"> Leontief, Wassily (September 1983). "Technological Advance, Economic Growth, and the Distribution of Income". Population and Development Review. 9 (3): 403–410. doi:10.2307/1973315. JSTOR 1973315.</ref>

Further reductions in working hours have been proposed as a possible solution to unemployment by economists including John R. Commons, Lord Keynes and Luigi Pasinetti. Yet once working hours have reached about 40 hours per week, workers have been less enthusiastic about further reductions, both to prevent loss of income and as many value engaging in work for its own sake[citation needed]. Generally, 20th-century economists had argued against further reductions as a solution to unemployment, saying it reflects a lump of labour fallacy.<ref>Walker, Tom (2007). "Why economists dislike a lump of labor". Review of Social Economy. 65 (3): 279–291. doi:10.1080/00346760701635809. S2CID 145673544. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref> In 2014, Google's co-founder, Larry Page, suggested a four-day workweek, so as technology continues to displace jobs, more people can find employment.<ref name=NYT-2014-12-15/><ref>Larry Page discusses his views on the socioeconomic effects of advanced intelligent systems and how advanced digital technologies can be used to create abundance (as described in Peter Diamandis' book), provide for people's needs, shorten the workweek, and mitigate any potential detrimental effects of technological unemployment. 2014-07-03. Discussion with Sergey Brin and Vinod Khosla. Starting at about 13:00 into the video. The audience is composed of the CEOs of the portfolio companies of Khosla Ventures.</ref><ref>Waters, Richard (31 October 2014). "FT interview with Google co-founder and CEO Larry Page". The Financial Times.</ref>

Public works

Programmes of public works have traditionally been used as way for governments to directly boost employment, though this has often been opposed by some, but not all, conservatives. Jean-Baptiste Say, although generally associated with free market economics, advised that public works could be a solution to technological unemployment.<ref>Baumol, William J. (2000). "Leontief's Great Leap Forward: Beyond Quesnay, Marx and von Bortkiewicz". Economic Systems Research. 12 (2): 141–152. doi:10.1080/09535310050005662. S2CID 154391578.</ref> Some commentators, such as professor Mathew Forstater, have advised that public works and guaranteed jobs in the public sector may be the ideal solution to technological unemployment, as unlike welfare or guaranteed income schemes they provide people with the social recognition and meaningful engagement that comes with work.<ref name = "unemployment history"> Forstater, Mathew (August 2001). "Unemployment in Capitalist Economies - A History of Thought for Thinking About Policy" (PDF). Center for Full Employment and Price Stability, University of Missouri–Kansas City. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref><ref name="better world">Forstater, Mathew (2015). "Working for a better world Cataloging arguments for the right to employment". Philosophy & Social Criticism. 41 (1): 61–67. doi:10.1177/0191453714553500. S2CID 145119895.</ref>

For less developed economies, public works may be an easier to administrate solution compared to universal welfare programmes.<ref name = "Advance"/> A partial exception is for spending on infrastructure, which has been recommended as a solution to technological unemployment even by economists previously associated with a neoliberal agenda, such as Larry Summers.<ref name = "Inclusive"> Balls, Ed; Lawrence Summers (co-chairs) (January 2015). "Report of the Commission on Inclusive Prosperity" (PDF). Center for American Progress. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref>

Education

Improved availability to quality education, including skills training for adults, is a solution that in principle at least is not opposed by any side of the political spectrum, and welcomed even by those who are optimistic about long-term technological employment. Improved education paid for by government tends to be especially popular with industry. However, several academics have argued that improved education alone will not be sufficient to solve technological unemployment, pointing to recent declines in the demand for many intermediate skills, and suggesting that not everyone is capable in becoming proficient in the most advanced skills.<ref name = "relative"/><ref name = "polarization"/><ref name="Reversal"/> Kim Taipale has said that "The era of bell curve distributions that supported a bulging social middle class is over... Education per se is not going to make up the difference."<ref name = "Power-curve"> David Bollier (January 2013). "POWER-CURVE SOCIETY: The Future of Innovation, Opportunity and Social Equity in the Emerging Networked Economy". The Aspen Institute. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref> while back in 2011 Paul Krugman argued that better education would be an insufficient solution to technological unemployment.<ref name = "Degrees"> Paul Krugman (March 2011). "Degrees and Dollars". The New York Times. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref>

Living with technological unemployment

Welfare payments

The use of various forms of subsidies has often been accepted as a solution to technological unemployment even by conservatives and by those who are optimistic about the long-term effect on jobs. Welfare programmes have historically tended to be more durable once established, compared with other solutions to unemployment such as directly creating jobs with public works. Despite being the first person to create a formal system describing compensation effects, Ramsey McCulloch and most other classical economists advocated government aid for those suffering from technological unemployment, as they understood that market adjustment to new technology was not instantaneous and that those displaced by labour-saving technology would not always be able to immediately obtain alternative employment through their own efforts.<ref name="Blaug 1997 loc= p182"/>

Basic income

Several commentators have argued that traditional forms of welfare payment may be inadequate as a response to the future challenges posed by technological unemployment, and have suggested a basic income as an alternative.<ref>Kaplan, Andreas; Haenlein, Michael (2019). "Siri, Siri, in my hand: Who's the fairest in the land? On the interpretations, illustrations, and implications of artificial intelligence". Business Horizons. 62: 15–25. doi:10.1016/j.bushor.2018.08.004. S2CID 158433736.</ref> People advocating some form of basic income as a solution to technological unemployment include Martin Ford, <ref>Ford 2009, passim, see esp. pp. 158–168</ref> Erik Brynjolfsson,<ref name="control"/> Robert Reich, Andrew Yang, Elon Musk, Zoltan Istvan, and Guy Standing. Reich has gone as far as to say the introduction of a basic income, perhaps implemented as a negative income tax is "almost inevitable",<ref>GleninCA (26 March 2014). "Robert Reich: Universal Basic Income in the US 'Almost Inevitable'". Daily Kos. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref> while Standing has said he considers that a basic income is becoming "politically essential".<ref name="paypressure">Chris Giles Sept, Sarah O’Connor, Claire Jones and Ben McLannahan (18 September 2014). "Pay pressure" (Template:Registration required). The Financial Times. Retrieved 14 July 2015.{{cite news}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)</ref> Since late 2015, new basic income pilots have been announced in Finland, the Netherlands, and Canada. Further recent advocacy for basic income has arisen from a number of technology entrepreneurs, the most prominent being Sam Altman, president of Y Combinator.<ref>Tarnoff, Ben (16 May 2016). "Tech billionaires got rich off us. Now they want to feed us the crumbs". The Guardian. London. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref>

Skepticism about basic income includes both right and left elements, and proposals for different forms of it have come from all segments of the spectrum. For example, while the best-known proposed forms (with taxation and distribution) are usually thought of as left-leaning ideas that right-leaning people try to defend against, other forms have been proposed even by libertarians, such as von Hayek and Friedman. In the United States, President Richard Nixon's Family Assistance Plan (FAP) of 1969, which had much in common with basic income, passed in the House but was defeated in the Senate.<ref name="Nixon1978">Nixon, Richard (1978). RN: The Memoirs of Richard Nixon. New York: Grosset & Dunlap. ISBN 978-0-448-14374-3.</ref>

One objection to basic income is that it could be a disincentive to work, but evidence from older pilots in India, Africa, and Canada indicates that this does not happen and that a basic income encourages low-level entrepreneurship and more productive, collaborative work. Another objection is that funding it sustainably is a huge challenge. While new revenue-raising ideas have been proposed such as Martin Ford's wage recapture tax, how to fund a generous basic income remains a debated question, and skeptics have dismissed it as utopian. Even from a progressive viewpoint, there are concerns that a basic income set too low may not help the economically vulnerable, especially if financed largely from cuts to other forms of welfare.<ref name="paypressure"/><ref>Ford 2009, pp.162-168.</ref><ref name = "MITRotman">Rotman, David (16 June 2015). "Who Will Own the Robots?". MIT. Archived from the original on 17 July 2015. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref><ref> Schneider, Nathan (January 2015). "Why the Tech Elite Is Getting Behind Universal Basic Income". Vice. Retrieved 14 July 2015. </ref>

To better address both the funding concerns and concerns about government control, one alternative model is that the cost and control would be distributed across the private sector instead of the public sector. Companies across the economy would be required to employ humans, but the job descriptions would be left to private innovation, and individuals would have to compete to be hired and retained. This would be a for-profit sector analog of basic income, that is, a market-based form of basic income. It differs from a job guarantee in that the government is not the employer (rather, companies are) and there is no aspect of having employees who "cannot be fired", a problem that interferes with economic dynamism. The economic salvation in this model is not that every individual is guaranteed a job, but rather just that enough jobs exist that massive unemployment is avoided and employment is no longer solely the privilege of only the very smartest or highly trained 20% of the population. Another option for a market-based form of basic income has been proposed by the Center for Economic and Social Justice (CESJ) as part of "a Just Third Way" (a Third Way with greater justice) through widely distributed power and liberty. Called the Capital Homestead Act,<ref name="Capital_Homestead_Act">Capital Homestead Act Summary, Center for Economic and Social Justice, archived from the original on 16 June 2017, retrieved 7 November 2015</ref> it is reminiscent of James S. Albus's Peoples' Capitalism<ref name="peoplescapbook"/><ref name="peoplescap"/> in that money creation and securities ownership are widely and directly distributed to individuals rather than flowing through, or being concentrated in, centralized or elite mechanisms.

Broadening the ownership of technological assets

Several solutions have been proposed which do not fall easily into the traditional left-right political spectrum. This includes broadening the ownership of robots and other productive capital assets. Enlarging the ownership of technologies has been advocated by people including James S. Albus<ref name="peoplescapbook"/><ref>"Dr. James Albus". James-albus.org. Archived from the original on 14 May 2013. Retrieved 28 March 2013.</ref> John Lanchester,<ref>Lanchester, John (March 2015). The Robots Are Coming, Vol. 37, No. 5, pages 3-8, London Review of Books</ref> Richard B. Freeman,<ref name = "MITRotman"/> and Noah Smith.<ref>Smith, Noah (14 January 2013). "The End of Labor: How to Protect Workers From the Rise of Robots". The Atlantic.</ref> Jaron Lanier has proposed a somewhat similar solution: a mechanism where ordinary people receive "nano payments" for the big data they generate by their regular surfing and other aspects of their online presence.<ref> Lanier, Jaron (2013). Who Owns the Future?. Allen Lane. p. passim, see esp p.20. ISBN 978-1846145223.</ref>

Structural changes towards a post-scarcity economy

The Zeitgeist Movement (TZM), The Venus Project (TVP) as well as various individuals and organizations propose structural changes towards a form of a post-scarcity economy in which people are 'freed' from their automatable, monotonous jobs, instead of 'losing' their jobs. In the system proposed by TZM all jobs are either automated, abolished for bringing no true value for society (such as ordinary advertising), rationalized by more efficient, sustainable and open processes and collaboration or carried out based on altruism and social relevance, opposed to compulsion or monetary gain.<ref name=tzm1>"The Zeitgeist Movement FAQ #5 - 2) Automation of Labor". Archived from the original on 15 August 2012. Retrieved 4 January 2017.</ref><ref>Feuer, Alan (16 March 2009). "Peter Joseph and Jacque Fresco Critique the Monetary Economy". The New York Times. Retrieved 5 January 2017.</ref><ref>The Zeitgeist Movement Defined: Realizing a New Train of Thought (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 13 January 2017. Retrieved 5 January 2017.</ref><ref>Simon, Alex (20 June 2015). "Awaiting Interreflections: Peter Joseph's Highly Anticipated New Film Series Inches Towards its 2016 Release". The Huffington Post. Retrieved 5 January 2017.</ref><ref>Donovan, Travis (16 May 2010). "The Zeitgeist Movement: Envisioning A Sustainable Future". The Huffington Post. Retrieved 5 January 2017.</ref> The movement also speculates that the free time made available to people will permit a renaissance of creativity, invention, community and social capital as well as reducing stress.<ref name=tzm1/>

Other approaches

The threat of technological unemployment has occasionally been used by free market economists as a justification for supply side reforms, to make it easier for employers to hire and fire workers. Conversely, it has also been used as a reason to justify an increase in employee protection.<ref name="Effective Demand">Cesaratto, Sergio; Stirati, Antonella; Serrano, Franklin (October 2001). "Technical Change, Effective Demand, and Employment". Center for Full Employment And Price Stability. Archived from the original on 23 September 2015. Retrieved 14 July 2015.</ref><ref name = The-Economist-2013-11-05>Labour's Declining Share - A Spectre to Worry About?, The Economist, 2013.11.05</ref>

Economists including Larry Summers have advised a package of measures may be needed. He advised vigorous cooperative efforts to address the "myriad devices" – such as tax havens, bank secrecy, money laundering, and regulatory arbitrage – which enable the holders of great wealth to avoid paying taxes, and to make it more difficult to accumulate great fortunes without requiring "great social contributions" in return. Summers suggested more vigorous enforcement of anti-monopoly laws; reductions in "excessive" protection for intellectual property; greater encouragement of profit-sharing schemes that may benefit workers and give them a stake in wealth accumulation; strengthening of collective bargaining arrangements; improvements in corporate governance; strengthening of financial regulation to eliminate subsidies to financial activity; easing of land-use restrictions that may cause estates to keep rising in value; better training for young people and retraining for displaced workers; and increased public and private investment in infrastructure development, such as energy production and transportation.<ref name="summers"/><ref name=NYT-2014-12-15/><ref name="inequalityPuzzle"/><ref>Turk, Victoria (19 June 2014). "Don't Fear the Robots Taking Your Job, Fear the Monopolies Behind Them". Vice.com.</ref>

Michael Spence has advised that responding to the future impact of technology will require a detailed understanding of the global forces and flows technology has set in motion. Adapting to them "will require shifts in mindsets, policies, investments (especially in human capital), and quite possibly models of employment and distribution".<ref group="note">Spence also wrote that "Now comes a ... powerful, wave of digital technology that is replacing labor in increasingly complex tasks. This process of labor substitution and disintermediation has been underway for some time in service sectors – think of ATMs, online banking, enterprise resource planning, customer relationship management, mobile payment systems, and much more. This revolution is spreading to the production of goods, where robots and 3D printing are displacing labor." In his view, the vast majority of the cost of digital technologies comes at the start, in the design of hardware (e.g. sensors) and, more important, in creating the software that enables machines to carry out various tasks. "Once this is achieved, the marginal cost of the hardware is relatively low (and declines as scale rises), and the marginal cost of replicating the software is essentially zero. With a huge potential global market to amortize the upfront fixed costs of design and testing, the incentives to invest [in digital technologies] are compelling." Spence believes that, unlike prior digital technologies, which drove firms to deploy underutilized pools of valuable labor around the world, the motivating force in the current wave of digital technologies "is cost reduction via the replacement of labor." For example, as the cost of 3D printing technology declines, it is "easy to imagine" that production may become "extremely" local and customized. Moreover, production may occur in response to actual demand, not anticipated or forecast demand. "Meanwhile, the impact of robotics ... is not confined to production. Though self-driving cars and drones are the most attention-getting examples, the impact on logistics is no less transformative. Computers and robotic cranes that schedule and move containers around and load ships now control the Port of Singapore, one of the most efficient in the world." Spence believes that labor, no matter how inexpensive, will become a less important asset for growth and employment expansion, with labor-intensive, process-oriented manufacturing becoming less effective, and that re-localization will appear globally. In his view, production will not disappear, but it will be less labor-intensive, and all countries will eventually need to rebuild their growth models around digital technologies and the human capital supporting their deployment and expansion.</ref><ref>Michael Spence, Labor’s Digital Displacement (2014-05-22), Project Syndicate</ref>

See also

Notes

<references group="note" responsive="1"></references>

References

Citations

<references group="" responsive="1"></references>

Sources

Template:Sfn whitelist

Further reading

Lua error in Module:Sister_project_links at line 469: attempt to index field 'wikibase' (a nil value).

Template:Employment Template:Basic income Template:Robotics